February 24, 2005
Australian Government
Rural Industries Research and
Development Corporation
Global Responses to GM Food
Technology: Implications for Australia
by
Kym Anderson
and Lee Ann Jackson
University of Adelaide
RIRDC Publication
No 05/016
RIRDC Project No UA-57A
February 2005
Executive Summary
Genetically modified organisms (GMOs) have great potential for
farmers and ultimately consumers in Australia and around the
world. Benefits for producers include greater productivity and
less occupational health and environmental damage (e.g., fewer
pesticides), while benefits to consumers include lower food
prices and, potentially, enhanced attributes (e.g.,
‘nutriceuticals’). Protagonists argue that genetic engineering
also entails a more-controlled transfer of genes because the
transfer is limited to selected genes, whereas traditional
breeding risks transferring unwanted genes together with the
desired ones.
Despite these potential
benefits, some consumer and community groups are concerned about
their potentially adverse impacts on food safety (e.g., ‘Will
they cause cancer?’) and the environment (e.g., ‘Will they lead
to pesticide-resistant superweeds?). Numerous governments are
responding to those concerns, typically in very conservative,
command-and-control ways such as banning the production and/or
use of GMOs or mandating strict GMO labelling laws. Countries
exporting food products fear that food-importing countries will
discount or deny access to their products if even a subset of
their farmers adopt GM technology. Indeed the European Union has
a moratorium – in place since October 1998 – on the approval of
GM products for domestic production or importation.
As a result, the US share of
the EU’s maize imports has fallen to virtually zero (from around
twothirds in the mid-1990s), as has Canada’s share of EU canola
imports (from 54 per cent in the mid- 1990s). The GM-adopting
countries have lost market share to GM-free suppliers
(particularly Brazil for maize and soybean and Australia and
Central Europe in the case of canola).
Food-exporting countries such
as Australia need to weigh the potential economic benefits from
biotechnology development against any net negative environmental
risks associated with producing GM crops, any additional costs
of segregation and identity preservation through the supply
chain, any discounting and/or loss of market access abroad for
conventional counterparts to those specific crops which may
contain GMOs, and any discounting and/or loss of market access
abroad for other farm products because of what GM adoption does
for Australia’s generic reputation as a ‘clean, green, safe
food’ producer. In addition, Australia has to decide whether to
participate in the current and possible future WTO dispute
settlement cases on GMOs, bearing in mind the risks this issue
brings to the rules-based global trading system in general and
the WTO’s farm trade reform agenda in particular.
All of Australia’s crop and
livestock producers, as well as consumers of these products,
have a direct economic interest in this issue. The adoption of
GM technology has been most widespread in the production of
maize, soybean and canola (key livestock feed ingredients
globally), as well as cotton.
As of 2002, GM varieties
accounted for one-quarter of the area planted to those crops
globally (and 4.3 per cent of all arable land), having been
close to zero prior to 1996. But most of it is grown in
Argentina, Canada and the United States, where that GM share is
more than 60 per cent. Production costs in those countries have
been lowered by more than 5 per cent, thereby lowering livestock
feedgrain costs and hence weakening the comparative advantage of
Australia’s competing grass-fed livestock industries (since
products from animals fed GM feedstuffs are not considered to
contain GMOs). GM rice and wheat are also possibilities in the
near future.
Neither the magnitude nor the
signs of the economic effects of GM adoption by some countries
and boycotts by others can be determined without empirical data
and a model of the affected markets.
This research uses the GTAP
model of the global economy to estimate the production, trade,
national economic welfare and real farm household income effects
in Australia and other countries of GM adoption. These GTAP
modelling results improve on earlier results in two respects: by
distinguishing between GM-free and GM-inclusive products, and by
generating real farm household income effects of technology
adoption and of consumer and government responses under various
scenarios. The latter results allow speculation as to the
motivation of governments in the US, EU and East Asia in
adopting different GM policies.
As mentioned above, maize,
soybean and canola have enjoyed the highest rate of adoption of
GM food varieties globally. The potential global benefits of GM
adoption in maize, soybean and canola is estimated to be
substantial (US$4.0 billion per year) if there were no adverse
reactions elsewhere.
However, as an exporter
Australia would gain, but only slightly, from adopting GM
varieties of these crops because the gain from higher crop
productivity would be almost fully offset by an adverse terms of
trade change. The EU moratorium, which acts as an increase in
farm protection there, causes the EU to be worse off by $3.1
billion per year (less whatever value EU consumers place on
having avoided consuming GM products), and reduces by two-thirds
the gain to the GM adopters. It improves welfare for
food-importing regions of the rest of the world and Australia
only very slightly.
If GM varieties of rice and
wheat were also to be released, quite possibly China and India
would then become GM adopters too. Since they account for 55 per
cent of the world’s rice market and 30 per cent of the wheat
market, the economic welfare effects of adding these two extra
countries and commodities are dramatic. The conservatively
estimated global economic welfare gain if there is no policy
response is $ $4.3 billion if rice and wheat are added and China
and India join the GMadopting group, almost double the current
gains from GM crop adoption. In this case if Australia chooses
not to adopt GM varieties, any gain in market access because of
the EU’s GM moratorium is almost fully offset by the greater
decline in international prices caused by the moratorium.
Australia’s crop production and
exports are reduced more, not less, as a result of the EU
moratorium.
On the other hand, if there
were no EU moratorium and Australia adopted GM technologies, its
crop production would expand instead of contracting. While
domestic consumption of crop and livestock products also would
increase because of lower domestic prices, those estimated
increases are not enough to prevent crop export earnings from
rising instead of falling. Hence net economic welfare for
Australia would be US$28 million per year higher as a result of
GM adoption, less any negative value domestic consumers place on
not knowing if they may be consuming GM products.
With the EU moratorium, the net
economic welfare benefit to Australian producers and consumers
of GM adoption in this case is estimated to be US$15 million per
year. While that is $13 million less than if there is no EU
moratorium, it still represents a net gain from joining the
adopters of GM varieties of these four crops even if the EU
moratorium remains in place. However, the average Australian
farm household income would decrease with GM adoption – even
with rice and wheat included – if the EU moratorium remains.
What should Australia do? The
consumer legislation on GMOs devised by the health ministers of
the Australian and New Zealand governments is relatively strict
by world standards in terms of tolerance of unintended GMO
material in foods sold in Australia, but it is more tolerant
with respect to products in which GMOs are no longer detectable.
Controls on Australian production of GM crop varieties were
already severe by North American and Argentinean standards, but
they are now constrained even further by domestic consumer
legislation. This has been well illustrated by the recent
debates over whether to approve GM canola production in
Australia: production is unlikely to be approved unless and
until an effective segregation and identity preservation system
is in place to allow co-existence of non-GM and GM varieties.
Even then, several States of Australia have continued to delay
approval because they perceive insufficient economic benefit
from GM crops to warrant the cost of the necessary co-existence
system (which will fall more on non-GM producers, the smaller
the share of GM varieties in total output) and the expected loss
that would result from a downgrading of their status as a
‘clean, green, safe food’ supplier domestically and abroad.
These cautious approaches were
understandable while only maize and soybean were ready for
adoption. The production ban is less defendable for canola now
that GM varieties for Australian conditions are available, and
will be even less so if and when suitable GM rice and wheat
varieties are ready for release and the concerns of consumers in
Europe and elsewhere fade, making adoption of these products
more economically beneficial. In revising Australian consumer
and producer regulations for dealing with GMO issues as
information and views evolve, the following points might be kept
in mind:
- Attitudes towards GMOs
(and many other attributes of food) are continually changing
as greater information becomes available to consumers, so
the optimal consumer regulation will change over time;
- In particular, consumer
attitudes towards GMOs will become more differentiated as
secondgeneration GM varieties come on stream that exhibit
product attributes specifically desired by consumers;
- The optimal regulation for
domestic sales depends to some extent on the costliness of a
segregation and identity preservation (SIP) system (since
consumers will bear part of its cost), the benefits of which
also depend on the consumer legislation that is still
developing in Australia’s export markets abroad;
- The demand by consumers
for foods with (or without) specific attributes will
continue to grow, so ‘GMO-ness’ is but one of many reasons
why consumers may be willing to pay for SIP systems in the
supply chain;
- Hence it may make less
sense in the future for a region to forego the productivity
gains in GM varieties if the main reason for that stance is
to avoid the costs of a SIP system, and particularly if the
region does not have the funds or organizational capacity to
promote itself as a GM-free region;
- Comparative advantages of
each region and of Australia as a whole in various (GM and
non- GM) crops will continue to change not only because of
changing consumer attitudes but also as countries alter
their consumer, producer and trade policies and as new GM
crop varieties appear;
- Where price premiums for
non-GM varieties exist they are small, meaning that the
market for certified non-GM foods may simply become a niche
market similar to the market for organics products;
- Crop varieties suited to
particular regions rarely appear as manna from heaven but
rather as a result of a concerted and targeted R&D
investment, so adopting a GM-free status will likely lead to
a bias toward more-traditional research which will tend to
be slower and hence less rewarding;
- Rural research and
development corporations can help to counter such tendencies
by ensuring a portion of their portfolio includes GM
technologies so that when markets become more accepting
those technologies can be disseminated relatively promptly;
- Australia’s biotech R&D
industry – a potential export earner in its own right –will
be held back the more Australia limits production of GM
crops, and as a result many scientists may choose to migrate
to more-stimulating research environments abroad;
- Industry groups can
prepare appropriate technology stewardship strategies, which
in turn will help investors who are thinking of developing
SIP systems;
- Fortunately the GMO
standards set by countries in East Asia, where much of
Australia’s food exports are destined, are less stringent
than Australia’s own standards; and
- Australia should oppose
excessive standards abroad if they are protectionist in
intent, for they may just be substitutes for traditional
protectionist measures as multilateral rounds of trade talks
lead to decreased use of traditional protectionist measures.
Full report in PDF format:
http://www.rirdc.gov.au/reports/GLC/05-016.pdf |